March 27,
2013, 11:32 AM EST
ByAlen
Mattich
The Wall
Street Journal
Remember
the Slinky, the toy spring that compresses and extends to walk down stairs,
bounce off tables and generally amuse children for minutes at a time?
Well, the
Slinky is a fair mechanical approximation of the euro zone economy.
Except it’s
not so entertaining.
In essence,
the nature of the euro’s one-size-fits-all monetary policy is bound to keep
member-state economies oscillating between compression and expansion–boom and
bust. That’s in part because of what, in retrospect, were misaligned valuations
when legacy currencies were converted to the euro. And also because the
constituent economies are likely to follow different cycles. Global
manufacturing, commodity and agricultural exports, and real estate and
construction cycles don’t move in tandem. And differing mixes of each of these
important components are likely to influence each economy’s pace of growth.
So
undervalued exchange rates and the sudden shock of historically low interest
rates set against the backdrop of often substantial public-sector deficits–the
size of which were at times obscured through the use of off-balance-sheet
accounting and derivatives–paved the way for credit booms across the single
currency’s perimeter.
Meanwhile Germany ,
struggling with reunification costs and a relatively expensive exchange rate,
threw itself into substantial economic restructuring.
And so,
during the first years of the euro, Spain ,
Ireland and Greece all
boomed, credit growth soared, with much of the money going into real estate and
construction.
We know how
that ended.
But as
Europe’s overleveraged countries struggled in the post-financial-crisis world, Germany
rebounded smartly. Put into a strong position by a decade of welfare reforms
that kept a lid on wages, and further boosted by developing-world demand for
high-value-added manufacturing, the German economy recovered smartly while much
of the rest of the euro zone floundered under the burden of debt and suddenly
overpriced labor.
Now what’s
happening is that Germany ’s
boom is finally starting to bring rising wage demands. German labor is becoming
ever less competitive at a time when depression, austerity and mass
unemployment are driving down labor costs in the countries that were previously
booming.
Very low
euro-zone interest rates coupled with strong wage growth and full employment
have set the stage for a German property boom. German house prices have been
accelerating, having been in the doldrums for decades. What’s more, Germans
“underown” housing–there’s a higher proportion of renters than in much of the
rest of Europe –and as they see house prices
advance and as ever more cheap mortgage credit is made available to them,
there’s every chance of an all-out boom. And the European Central Bank, eyes on
depressions elsewhere in the single-currency region, won’t be in much of a
position to take the heat out of the German economy, much as the ECB failed to
control the Spanish and Irish booms because of Germany ’s long post-unification
convalescence.
If Germany now is where Ireland
and Spain were in the late
1990s, Ireland and Spain are where Germany was. Painful economic
restructuring is paving the way for a slow-build shift to exports from domestic
consumption. How quickly this adjustment comes depends on the degree to which Germany ’s
consumption and property upsurge gets under way. But the trends are being
locked in place. The Slinky spring’s compression and expansion waves are in
train.
How long Europeans
tolerate these boom-bust cycles that are exacerbated by the ECB’s inability to
respond to local factors is another matter. Eventually, children become bored
with the Slinky and stretch it all out of shape.
No comments:
Post a Comment