By SERGEI GURIEVDEC. 9, 2015
The
New York Times
As a
political economist, I make my living studying the impact of politics on
economics. My friends and co-authors who are political scientists focus on how
economics affects politics. Which is more relevant in real life? Do countries
with bad politics suffer from poor economic outcomes because bad economic
policies are driven by bad politics? Or because persistent economic
difficulties make reasonable politics hard to sustain?
Every year
offers examples of both kinds. The year 2015 was no exception, producing two
very important stories: Greece
and China .
Both are dramatic and multifaceted.
In Greece , the
cradle of Western democracy, voters became disappointed with mainstream parties
and elected the small leftist Syriza party, which promised deliverance from
economic pain. Critics from nondemocratic regimes (or from “illiberal
democracies”) interpreted Syriza’s victory as a failure of the democratic
system. They argued that it was proof that ordinary voters could not be trusted
with important decisions because they prefer simple but incorrect populist
solutions. However, the events following Syriza’s victory showed that Greek
voters were not shortsighted or irrational.
Yes, as
soon became clear, Syriza’s promises were not realistic. As the former U.S.
Treasury Secretary Larry Summers once said, “You can’t repeal the laws of
economics. Even if they are inconvenient.” However popular Syriza was, it could
not conjure up billions of euros out of thin air.
The choice
was to continue with painful reforms or to default. Reform would mean an
immediate decline in living standards; default would make things even worse.
Default always brings turbulence and uncertainty, and the government would
automatically switch to austerity policies anyway — not because it wanted to,
but because it would have no cash to do anything else. There would simply be no
access to financial markets.
I am old
enough to remember how the 1998 default in Russia brought to power the only
openly leftist government in the country’s post-Soviet history. It initially
spouted Communist rhetoric but was forced by lack of cash to implement one of
the most austere budgets that Russia
has ever had.
Greek
voters apparently understood the cost of default and, in a referendum, strongly
supported staying in the eurozone. This vote eventually pushed the Syriza
government into reaching a deal with the country’s creditors. The deal will not
bring prosperity to the Greek voters, but it is certainly the least costly
option.
The other,
even bigger, economic story of the year was China ’s stock market crash and
slowdown in economic growth. The striking success of China ’s economy since 1978, as the
government has implemented economic reforms, has puzzled many economists and
political scientists. Dictatorships usually suffer from two imminent problems.
One, in nondemocracies it is hard to create a genuine rule-of-law, which is
crucial for property rights and contract enforcement; these in turn are
necessary for investment and growth. Usually dictatorial governments cannot
commit to abstain from expropriating investors. Two, without political
competition and media freedom it is hard to get proper feedback, which is
needed for running a large country.
The Chinese
Communist Party addressed these problems to a certain extent by adopting
several essential elements of modern democratic politics: meritocracy, checks
and balances, and regular elite rotation. The jury is still out on how and why
this system emerged. It may well be that the period 1949 to 1978 was just a
blip, after which China returned to its Confucian meritocratic institutions, or
it may be that the survivors of the Mao era wanted to build safeguards against
its return.
This hybrid
political system created incentives for pro-growth reforms: liberalization in
agriculture and then in other sectors; relaxation of barriers to internal
migration; privatization of small firms and then of larger ones; and
integration into the global economy. These reforms brought a growth trajectory
similar to those in Japan , Taiwan and South Korea 15 to 30 years earlier.
However,
those countries already had more open political systems when they reached the
income levels that China
enjoys today. This openness in turn allowed them to continue with reforms that
brought further growth. That is not a coincidence: Economic theory holds that
there is a qualitative difference between growth from a poor into a
middle-income country and further growth from middle-income to rich. The former
involves catching up with advanced countries and adopting their “best
practices”; this process may be carried out in a top-down fashion. So a
“benevolent” centralized government can do the job.
As for the
above-middle-income growth, the economic system needs to encourage innovation,
which requires a decentralized, competitive political system. Many countries
have not managed to build such pro-innovation institutions and then got stuck
in the “middle-income-trap” of growth slowdown. Japan ,
Taiwan and Korea overcame
this trap and became knowledge-based, rich economies.
The
turbulence of 2015 indicated that China may be facing this challenge.
Multiple economic studies have shown that China still has huge potential for
growth that can be unlocked by further reforms in the state-owned enterprises
and the financial system, promoting the rule of law and competition policies.
But such reforms could undermine the current government’s hold on power because
those enterprises and banks are its main economic levers.
In 2012, China ’s incoming leaders outlined a reform
agenda in an impressive “China 2030” blueprint co-authored by China ’s State
Council and the World Bank. In the past three years, however, very little of
that road map has been implemented. Instead, China ’s leaders have opted for
greater centralization of political power.
The debate
over whether democracy delivers prosperity dates back at least to Aristotle —
social scientists have always asked whether democracy promotes economic growth,
or high incomes are a prerequisite for a stable democracy. In recent years,
economists have used advanced statistical tools to show that the first view is
correct: Countries undergoing democratizations on average improve their growth
performance by 1 or 2 percent per year for 10 years.
The year
2015 suggests they are probably right. Greek voters chose the lesser evil,
however painful. And China ’s
troubles suggested that the Chinese political system may be somewhat outdated
for what its economy needs and deserves. This does not imply that Greece ’s economic growth will outperform China ’s. It
won’t — as there are many things that Greece
can learn from China .
But this year has also shown that China
can also learn from Greece :
Voters are not always wrong and top-down rulers are not always benevolent,
omniscient and omnipotent.
Sergei
Guriev is professor of economics at the Instituts d’études politiques
(SciencesPo) in Paris .
He was formerly rector of the New Economic School
in Moscow but left Russia under political pressure.
No comments:
Post a Comment