Kenneth Rogoff
Some
eurozone policymakers seem to be confident that a Greek exit from the euro,
hard or soft, will no longer pose a threat to the other periphery countries.
They might be right; then again, back in 2008, US policymakers thought that the
collapse of one investment house, Bear Stearns, had prepared markets for the
bankruptcy of another, Lehman Brothers. We know how that turned out.
True, there
have been some important policy and institutional advances since early 2010,
when the Greek crisis first began to unfold. The new banking union, however
imperfect, and the European Central Bank’s vow to save the euro by doing
“whatever it takes,” are essential to sustaining the monetary union. Another
crucial innovation has been the development of the European Stability
Mechanism, which, like the International Monetary Fund, has the capacity to
execute vast financial bailouts, subject to conditionality.
And yet,
even with these new institutional backstops, the global financial risks of Greece ’s
instability remain profound. It is not hard to imagine Greece ’s brash new leaders underestimating Germany ’s
intransigence on debt relief or renegotiation of structural-reform packages. It
is also not hard to imagine Eurocrats miscalculating political dynamics in Greece .
In any
scenario, most of the burden of adjustment will fall on Greece . Any
profligate country that is suddenly forced to live within its means has a huge
adjustment to make, even if all of its past debts are forgiven. And Greece ’s
profligacy was epic. In the run-up to its debt crisis in 2010, the government’s
primary budget deficit (the amount by which government expenditure on goods and
services exceeds revenues, excluding interest payments on its debt) was
equivalent to an astonishing 10% of national income.
Once the
crisis erupted and Greece
lost access to new private lending, the “troika” (the IMF, the ECB, and the
European Commission) provided massively subsidized long-term financing. But
even if Greece ’s
debt had been completely wiped out, going from a primary deficit of 10% of GDP
to a balanced budget requires massive belt tightening – and, inevitably,
recession. Germans have a point when they argue that complaints about
“austerity” ought to be directed at Greece ’s previous governments.
These governments’ excesses lifted Greek consumption far above a sustainable
level; a fall to earth was unavoidable.
Nonetheless,
Europe needs to be much more generous in
permanently writing down debt and, even more urgently, in reducing short-term
repayment flows. The first is necessary to reduce long-term uncertainty; the
second is essential to facilitate near-term growth.
Let’s face
it: Greece ’s
bind today is hardly all of its own making. (Greece ’s young people – who now
often take a couple of extra years to complete college, because their teachers
are so often on strike – certainly did not cause it.)
First and
foremost, the eurozone countries’ decision to admit Greece to the single currency in
2002 was woefully irresponsible, with French advocacy deserving much of the
blame. Back then, Greece
conspicuously failed to meet a plethora of basic convergence criteria, owing to
its massive debt and its relative economic and political backwardness.
Second,
much of the financing for Greece ’s
debts came from German and French banks that earned huge profits by
intermediating loans from their own countries and from Asia .
They poured this money into a fragile state whose fiscal credibility ultimately
rested on being bailed out by other euro members.
Third, Greece ’s
eurozone partners wield a massive stick that is typically absent in
sovereign-debt negotiations. If Greece
does not accept the conditions imposed on it to maintain its membership in the
single currency, it risks being thrown out of the European Union altogether.
Even after
two bailout packages, it is unrealistic to expect Greek taxpayers to start
making large repayments anytime soon – not with unemployment at 25% (and above
50% for young people). Germany
and other hawkish northern Europeans are right to insist that Greece adhere
to its commitments on structural reform, so that economic convergence with the
rest of the eurozone can occur one day. But they ought to be making even deeper
concessions on debt repayments, where the overhang still creates considerable
policy uncertainty for investors.
If
concessions to Greece
create a precedent that other countries might exploit, so be it. Sooner rather
than later, other periphery countries will also need help. Greece , one
hopes, will not be forced to leave the eurozone, though temporary options such
as imposing capital controls may ultimately prove necessary to prevent a
financial meltdown. The eurozone must continue to bend, if it is not to break.
Read more
at
http://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/greek-exit-syriza-troika-negotiations-by-kenneth-rogoff-2015-02#6elh71D8TsFtMLD4.99
Kenneth
Rogoff, Professor of Economics and Public Policy at Harvard University
and recipient of the 2011 Deutsche Bank Prize in Financial Economics, was the
chief economist of the International Monetary Fund from 2001 to 2003. His most
recent book, co-authored with Carmen M. Reinhart, is This Time is Different:
Eight Centuries of Financial Folly.
Read more at
http://www.project-syndicate.org/columnist/kenneth-rogoff#C1pDl6UyxfC6qQYE.99
No comments:
Post a Comment