The euro
crisis was not a government-debt crisis
Nov 23rd
2015, 9:43 BY R.A. | LONDON
The
Economist
THE
euro-zone crisis has transitioned from an acute phase to a chronic one. At just
this moment the fear that market panic might force one or several economies out
of the single currency is low. Yet few analysts believe the euro zone has
solved its fundamental problems. In a piece published at Vox EU last week, a
cadre of prominent economists made the very sensible point that unless
euro-area leaders can agree on the fundamental causes of the crisis, they will
struggle to craft long-run fixes. The authors set out their view of the crisis,
in hopes that it will prove a foundation for consensus building.
Their
explanation, which strikes me as the right one, is that the euro-area crisis
was not a sovereign-debt crisis. If it had been, one would have expected Belgium and Italy , which entered the crisis
with extraordinarily high debts, to have landed in serious trouble. As it
turned out, they made it through without troika programmes, while Ireland and Spain , which entered the crisis
with low levels of sovereign debt, needed bail-outs. The problem, instead, was
one of massive capital flows across borders, which encouraged high levels of private
borrowing in the economies that eventually got into trouble. When the global
financial crisis generated a reversal in those flows, private borrowers and
banks got into big trouble. That trouble translated into serious economic
downturns and bank failures, both of which led to explosive growth in sovereign
debt burdens.
Exploding
sovereign debt was the symptom rather than the cause of the crisis. It is worth
pointing out that Europe 's current financial
calm is not a result of the fact that European economies have brought down
their sovereign-debt burdens. Public debt loads are bigger now than they were
in 2010, not smaller. (Germany
is a notable exception). And while euro-area economies have engaged in
austerity, several continue to miss their budget targets. Bond yields have
plummeted not because of the return of fiscal sobriety, but because the
European Central Bank is buying loads of public debt and has promised to do
what it takes to keep the euro-area together.
Why, then,
has the crisis response been so focused on sovereign borrowing? It probably
mattered that the first country to get into trouble was Greece , which
did have a big public-debt problem in addition to its other woes. At 129% of
GDP in 2009, Greek public debt was (and remains) the highest in the euro area.
The crisis narrative therefore centred on public debt as a crisis
indicator—outside the euro area as well as inside it. Britain 's
austerity push was predicated in part on the notion that it could run into
Greece-like trouble. America 's
pivot to austerity was similarly influenced by the Greek mess.
This
fundamentally missed the point. Italy 's
debt is now larger, as a share of GDP, than Greece 's was when it got into
trouble. But the yield on Italian debt is now below the yield on American
Treasuries.
The
misdiagnosis had significant consequences for the trajectory of the crisis.
Austerity around the periphery might have been a political-economy necessity—a
prerequisite for German acquiescence to ECB debt-buying. It was not an economic
necessity. The euro-area downturn was much deeper than it needed to be, and the
prospects for a euro-area exit from the zero-interest-rate world are perhaps
the worst in the world now—worse, potentially, than the outlook for Japan .
Yet the
really disconcerting thing is that while the crisis response (and in particular
the steps taken by the ECB to backstop euro-area banks and sovereigns) reduced
the threat of scenario in which a market panic causes the ejection of a member
country, it reinforced the macroeconomic rigidity of the single-currency area.
It was already the case that member states could not set their own monetary
policy or devalue to help manage a recession. Now, Europe
has moved toward much more stringent budget rules, as well, in the form of the
2012 Fiscal Compact, which tightens the fiscal rules initially agreed in the
Stability and Growth Pact and gives the euro area oversight of individual
country budgets.
The euro
area has stripped away the shock absorbers most economies rely on to reduce the
negative effects of demand shocks, and saddled the monetary union with a
central bank that is politically unable to respond in dramatic fashion to an
economic downturn in the absence of obvious deflationary pressures. That's not
a good place for an economy to be. If the euro-area is now safer from markets
than it was pre-crisis, it is more vulnerable to the political backlash that
will inevitably result, in one country or another, at some time or another,
when the strictures of Europe 's monetary union
become too painful to put up with any longer.
http://www.economist.com/blogs/freeexchange/2015/11/disagreement-europe
No comments:
Post a Comment