Despite
modest debt and a competitive economy, the Nordic country is on course for a
fourth year of recession, but don’t blame the common currency
The Wall
Street Journal
By SIMON
NIXON
Nov. 25,
2015 5:30 p.m. ET
8 COMMENTS
Which has
been the worst performing economy in Europe this year, excluding Greece ? The
surprising answer is Finland .
In the third quarter of this year, Finland ’s economy contracted by
0.6%, putting it on course for a possible fourth consecutive year of recession.
Since 2008, its output has shrunk by 6%, faring only slightly better than Italy ’s roughly
8% decline over the same period.
This might
seem an odd record for a country whose sovereign debt still enjoys the rare
accolade of a Triple-A rating, whose government debt-to-GDP ratio remains a
relatively modest 62%, and which didn’t experience a banking bust. Finland is
ranked by the World Economic Forum among the top 10 most competitive economies
in the world, and its governments have taken a consistently hard line toward
eurozone crisis countries. Now it looks increasingly like a stressed economy
itself. How has this happened?
The
simplistic answer is to blame the euro, which hardly helped the country deal
with a series of shocks in recent years: the implosion of Nokia, Finland’s
biggest employer; the collapse of the paper industry, reflecting the decline of
newspapers and the bursting of the commodity bubble; the euro crisis and the
European Union’s Russian sanctions regime, which hit Finland’s biggest export
markets. The cumulative result is that Finland ’s export market share has
shrunk by a third since 2008, wiping out what was a large current-account
surplus and accounting for much of the decline in growth.
If Finland had
retained its own currency, it could have responded to these shocks by devaluing
to regain competitiveness, as it did in the aftermath of its financial crisis
in the 1990s. The U.K. and Sweden , which
did devalue in the early stages of the 2008 global financial crisis, have seen
GDP rise by 6% and 8% respectively since then. In contrast, Finland has
been forced to attempt a painful internal devaluation, trying to regain
competitiveness by forcing down labor costs through wage cuts and austerity.
Paavo Vayrynen, a former foreign minister and now a member of the European
Parliament, has collected 50,000 signatures for a petition demanding that the
Finnish parliament debate whether the country should exit the euro.
But this
explanation doesn’t tell the whole story. First, it is easy to exaggerate the
role devaluation played in the British and Swedish recoveries. The U.K. recovery
began only as its substantial postcrisis devaluation started to reverse. In a
world of increasingly open economies and interconnected supply chains, the
benefits of devaluations aren’t clear-cut, potentially pushing up manufacturing
costs and depressing consumer demand. Conversely, two of the fastest-growing
economies in the EU now are Ireland
and Spain ,
both of which are in the eurozone.
Second, Finland ’s euro
membership has allowed it to benefit from unprecedentedly low funding costs
since the start of the euro crisis, unlike other stressed eurozone countries
that saw their funding costs soar. That reflects Finland ’s high levels of fiscal
credibility, based on its low debt and deficits and its commitment to complying
with the eurozone’s fiscal rules. It is an open question what would have
happened to Finland ’s
funding costs had it retained its own currency and tried to devalue and spend
its way back to growth.
The more
pertinent question is why Finland ’s
current ultralow funding costs haven’t helped fuel a recovery. The answer lies
in the structure of Finland ’s
economy. What the U.K. , Ireland , Sweden
and—to a lesser extent—Spain
have in common is that they have all taken steps over the past decade and more
to make their economies more flexible. Sweden , for example, has in recent
years largely abandoned the traditional Scandinavian model: Public spending has
been cut from over 60% of GDP in the mid-1990s to just over 50% now, the top
rate of tax cut from over 85% to 56%, and the tax and benefits system
completely overhauled to spur those of working age to take jobs. Sweden ’s
renaissance owes far more to comprehensive free-market structural reforms than
it does to devaluation.
In
contrast, Finland ’s economy
today more closely resembles that of France
than Sweden .
Its public spending and tax revenues account for an eye-watering 59% and 56% of
GDP respectively, higher even than France ’s. Its labor market is one
of the most rigid in the world, ranked 103rd out of 144 countries for labor
flexibility in 2015 by the World Economic Forum. That explains why labor costs
continued to soar even as the economy dived and productivity tanked; Finnish
unit labor costs are now 20% higher than those of Germany . And thanks to Finland’s
highly generous benefits system, the proportion of the working-age population
that is economically active is five percentage points below that in Sweden—a
serious problem for a country whose workforce is already shrinking as a result
of having the worst demographic profile in the EU.
Finland’s
challenge is to undertake the kind of deep structural reforms of its public
sector, labor rules and welfare system necessary to enable it to compete in an
open, global economy—as its new center-right coalition government is trying to
do. This would be essential regardless of whether the country was in the euro
or not. Indeed, quitting the euro would arguably incur very substantial
short-term costs for limited gain—a point clearly not lost on all Finland’s
major political parties and the 62% of its voters who polls show continue to
support euro membership despite the continuing slump.
No comments:
Post a Comment