5 JUL 27,
2015 2:00 AM EDT
By Barry
Eichengreen , Peter T. Allen & Gary Evans
Greece's
debt is unsustainable. The International Monetary Fund has said so, and it's
hard to find anyone who disagrees. The Greek government sees structural reform
without debt reduction as politically and economically toxic. The main
governing party, Syriza, has made debt reduction a central plank of its
electoral platform and will find it hard to hold on to power -- much less
implement painful structural measures -- absent this achievement.
Moreover,
tax increases and spending cuts by themselves will only deepen the Greek slump.
Other measures are needed to attract the investment required to jump-start
growth. Reducing the debt and its implicit claim on future incomes is an
obvious first step.
But German
Finance Minister Wolfgang Schaeuble and Chancellor Angela Merkel refuse to
consider any cut in the nominal stock of Greece's debt to the European Union.
They refuse to agree to debt-service reductions without prior structural
reforms. In their view, lower interest rates, grace periods and more generous
amortization terms should be a reward for prior action on the structural front.
If they are offered now, Greece will only be let off the hook.
There's an
obvious way of squaring this circle: Greece and the EU should contractually
link changes in the terms of the country's EU loans to milestones in structural
reform. Think of the result as structural-reform-indexed (SRI) loans, akin to
former Greek Finance Minister Yanis Varoufakis's gross-domestic-product-indexed
bonds.
Under the
new loan terms, if Greece implements more reforms, future interest payments
would be permanently lower and principal payments would be extended
indefinitely. Full implementation of the specified reforms would turn Greece's
debt into the equivalent of zero-coupon, infinitely lived bonds that drain
little if anything from the public purse.
Greece
should welcome this arrangement, because it would receive a guarantee of debt
reduction, not just vague reassurances. The German government and other
creditors should welcome it as well, because debt reduction would only be
conferred if Greece follows through with structural reform. Both sides would
appreciate that Greece's incentive to push ahead with reforms would be
heightened insofar as successful reform conferred an additional reward.
Even
better, Euro-group members could convert their bilateral loans and European
Financial Stability Facility/European Stability Mechanism funding for Greece
into SRI bonds. These could then be used for debt-for-equity swaps with private
investors and for other forms of investment-friendly debt conversion.
There is
precedent for this kind of arrangement. In 1991, Western governments,
negotiating as the Paris Club, offered Poland a deal in which debt reduction
was linked to structural reform. In the first stage, Poland received a 30
percent cut in the present value of its debt in return for agreeing with the
IMF on the terms of a structural adjustment program. In the second stage,
Poland received a further 20 percent cut contingent -- importantly -- on
fulfillment of the structural conditions of its IMF program.
The second
stage was also contingent on Poland negotiating a comparable reduction,
totaling 50 percent, in its privately held debt. In Greece's case, this element
is conveniently already in place, as Greece's private bondholders already had
their holdings "haircutted" by some 60 percent in 2012.
As a result, as in Poland in 1991, the majority of the
troubled country's debt is in official hands. This makes the kind of
contractual agreement we propose relatively straightforward to arrange.
Converting Greece's debt into SRI bonds would have to
surmount two hurdles. First, the parties would have to specify a list of
reforms and a corresponding timeline, and incorporate these into their debt
contact. Agreeing on a comprehensive list of reforms and the priority attached
to each would not be straightforward. But doing so would be a valuable form of
intellectual discipline. Asking the Greek authorities to do everything, without
a timeline and without attaching degrees of importance to different policy
measures, is easy. Specifying corresponding weights and schedules --
prioritizing, in other words -- is harder, but no less important for the fact.
Second, there would have to be an impartial body to monitor
and verify implementation of the measures. In Poland's 1991 debt deal, the IMF
played this role. But the Greek government doubts the fund's impartiality, not
least because the IMF itself is a not-entirely-disinterested creditor. It would
be better under the circumstances for implementation to be verified by a panel
of three independent experts: one nominated by the Greek government, one
nominated by the Euro group and one acceptable to both parties.
A final noteworthy aspect of the 1991 deal is that Poland's
principal creditor at the time was none other than Germany. That Germany has
seen this kind of arrangement before is one reason it should consider it again.
This column does not necessarily reflect the opinion of the
editorial board or Bloomberg LP and its owners.
To contact the authors on this story:
Barry Eichengreen at eichengr@econ.berkeley.edu
Peter Allen at peterallen@vom.com
Gary Evans at gevans33@msn.com
To contact the editor on this story:
Tracy Walsh
at twalsh67@bloomberg.net
No comments:
Post a Comment