MAR 3, 2015
32
Project
Syndicate
By Ricardo
Hausmann
For
example, Joseph Stiglitz regards austerity in Greece
as a matter of ideological choice or bad economics, just like in the US . According
to this view, those who favor austerity must be obsessed with the theory, given
the availability of a kinder, gentler alternative. Why would you ever vote for
austerity when parties like Greece 's
Syriza or Spain 's
Podemos offer a pain-free path?
The
question reflects a lamentable tendency to conflate two very different
situations. In the US ,
the issue was whether a government that could borrow at record-low interest
rates, in the middle of a recession, should do so. By contrast, Greece piled up
an enormous fiscal and external debt in boom times, until markets said
“enough" in 2009.
But the
truth is that the recession in Greece
has little to do with an excessive debt burden. Until 2014, the country did not
pay, in net terms, a single euro in interest: it borrowed enough from official
sources at subsidized rates to pay 100% of its interest bill and then some.
This situation supposedly changed a bit in 2014, the first year that the
country made a small contribution to its interest bill, having run a primary
surplus of barely 0.8% of GDP (or 0.5% of its debt of 170% of GDP).
Recent
advances in behavioral economics show that we all have enormous problems with
self-control. And game theory explains why we act even more irresponsibly when
making group decisions (owing to the so-called common pool problem). Fiscal
deficits, like unwanted pregnancies, are the unintended consequence of actions
taken by more than one person who had other objectives in mind. And lack of
fiscal control is what got Greece
into trouble in the first place.
So the
problem is not that austerity was tried and failed in Greece . It is
that, despite unprecedented international generosity, fiscal policy was
completely out of control and needed major adjustments. Insufficient spending
was never an issue. From 1998 to 2007, Greece 's
annual per capita GDP growth averaged 3.8%, the second fastest in Western
Europe, behind only Ireland .
But by
2007, Greece was spending
more than 14% of GDP in excess of what it was producing, the largest such gap
in Europe – more than twice that of Spain
and 55% higher than Ireland 's.
In Spain and Ireland ,
though, the gap reflected a construction boom; euro accession suddenly gave
people access to much cheaper mortgages. In Greece , by contrast, the gap was
mostly fiscal and used for consumption, not investment.
Unsustainable
growth paths often end in a sudden stop of capital inflows, forcing countries
to bring their spending back in line with production. In Greece , however, official lenders' unprecedented
munificence made the adjustment more gradual than in, say, Latvia or Ireland . In fact, even after the
so-called Greek Depression, its economy has grown more in per capita terms
since 1998 than Cyprus , Denmark , Italy ,
and Portugal .
Sudden
stops are always painful: economics has not discovered a hangover cure. But the
way to minimize the pain is to cut spending without cutting output, which
requires selling to others what residents can no longer afford. In other words,
unless Greece
boosts exports, spending cuts will amplify the output loss in the same way that
Keynesian multipliers amplified the output gain from borrowing.
The problem
is that Greece
produces very little of what the world wants to consume. Its exports of goods
comprise mainly fruits, olive oil, raw cotton, tobacco, and some refined
petroleum products. Germany ,
which many argue should spend more, imports just 0.2% of its goods from Greece . Tourism
is a mature industry with plenty of regional competitors. The country produces
no machines, electronics, or chemicals. Of every $10 of world trade in
information technology, Greece
accounts for $0.01.
Too much of
the debate since then has focused on what Germany , the EU, or the
International Monetary Fund must do. But the bottom line is that Greece needs to
develop its productive capabilities if it wants to grow. The unfocused set of
structural reforms prescribed by its current financing agreement will not do
that. Instead, Greece should
concentrate on activist policies that attract globally competitive firms, an
area where Ireland
has much to teach – and where Stiglitz has sensible things to say.
Unfortunately,
this is not what many Greeks (or Spaniards) believe. A large plurality of them
voted for Syriza, which wants to reallocate resources to wage increases and
subsidies and does not even mention exports in its growth strategy. They would
be wise to remember that having Stiglitz as a cheerleader and Podemos as
advisers did not save Venezuela
from its current hyper-inflationary catastrophe.
Read more
at
http://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/greece-export-problem-by-ricardo-hausmann-2015-03#jKuVCP8apmmFtUcB.99
Ricardo
Hausmann, a former minister of planning of Venezuela
and former Chief Economist of the Inter-American Development Bank, is Professor
of the Practice of Economic Development at Harvard University ,
where he is also Director of the Center for International Development. He is
Chair of the World Economic Forum's Global Agenda Meta-Council on Inclusive
Growth.
It'sgoing to be end of minne day, except before ending I am reading this wonderfuul piece of
ReplyDeletewriting to improve my know-how.
My site ... m88 ผ่าน iphone; https://www.m88u.com/,