http://www.voxeu.org/article/greece-no-escape-inevitable
by Lars P
Feld, Christoph M Schmidt, Isabel Schnabel, Benjamin Weigert, Volker Wieland
20
February 2015
Claims that
‘austerity has failed’ are popular, especially in the Anglo-Saxon world. This
column argues that this narrative is factually wrong and ignores the reasons
underlying the Greek crisis. The worst move for Greece would be to return to its
old ways. Greece
needs to realise that things could actually become much worse than they are
now, particularly if membership in the Eurozone cannot be assured. Instead of
looking back, Greece
needs to continue building a functioning state and a functioning market
economy.
‘Austerity
has failed’ is the most popular narrative of many commentators, especially in
the Anglo-Saxon world and in the European periphery (e.g. Stiglitz 2015, Wolf
2013), and it now serves as the principal argument for the Greek government in
its request to renegotiate the adjustment part of the European rescue package
(for an introduction to the austerity debate, see Corsetti 2012). This
narrative is factually wrong and ignores the reasons underlying the Greek
crisis.
To
understand that fiscal consolidation was inevitable and would have been an
integral part of any policy option, it is instructive to recall the situation
in 2009/10. At the end of 2009 the then newly elected Greek government revised
its projected budget deficit figures – an announcement that sent financial
markets into turmoil. At that time, Greece ’s macroeconomic fundamentals
were simply catastrophic. After years of fiscal profligacy the budget deficit
stood at 15% of GDP – with the primary deficit (when ignoring interest
payments) at 10% – and the debt ratio amounted to 127%. The current account
deficit stood at 10% of GDP, while net international debt amounted to 87%.
Given these
fundamentals there was only one policy option – Greece had to balance its budget,
and the current account needed to be turned into a surplus, to be able to
service both its private and public debt. Defaulting on outstanding debt would
not have obviated the need to rebalance the economy and the fiscal position,
since the budget deficit was huge even without considering interest payments.
With the
adjustment programme, Greece
entered into a loan agreement with its European partners, which was designed to
allow Greece
to stretch the economic adjustment over time (European Commission 2012).
Funding was supplied in exchange for fiscal consolidation and economic reforms.
What particular kind of reforms would be implemented and who would bear the
cost of adjustment was entirely determined by the Greek government. Reforms
only had to add up to a sufficient overall adjustment.
The
implementation plans devised by the Greek government were to be supervised by
the creditors, aka the Troika, but not dictated in detail. This supervision
merely served the objective of ascertaining that the chosen combination of
fiscal consolidation and economic reform would deliver the aggregate adjustment
that was necessary to bring Greece
back on a sustainable growth and debt path. From the perspective of the
(democratically legitimised) parliaments of the creditor states, there was
hardly any alternative to such an arrangement combining generous loans with
careful supervision.
A
counterfactual world
For an
economy in the dismal Greek situation, it essentially made no difference that
it remained a member of the Eurozone – in any case, adjustment was unavoidable,
and it would be painful and accompanied by strong social tensions. The
adjustment process of countries that experienced debt and currency crises
follows a very similar pattern. This is irrespective of whether they
successfully defended a fixed exchange rate or allowed their exchange rate to
devalue in order to support external economic adjustment. In all cases we
observe a crisis-driven current account adjustment in connection with a deep
slump and subsequent recovery of GDP. Nearly all countries depicted here
experienced sharp increases in unemployment, which started to decline only when
growth picked up.
It is
particularly instructive to consider the adjustment of the Baltic states, which
defended their fixed exchange rates and, in the case of Latvia ,
received balance-of-payments assistance from the EU and the IMF in exchange for
an adjustment programme (see Purfield and Rosenberg 2010). Since in all these
cases painful adjustment was inevitable and costly, one should take the
combination of the rescue packages and adjustment programmes as what they
really are – a device helping to avoid a sudden fiscal and current account
adjustment with even larger immediate pain. This also holds for Greece .
Necessary steps were stretched over time, and growth-enhancing reforms should
compensate the loss in demand previously financed by public debt. Thus, the
root cause of the painful adjustment is past profligacy and not the adjustment
programme.
Adjustment
progress: The glass is half full
During the
past five years Greece
indeed underwent serious reforms and fiscal consolidation. Progress has been
remarkable but incomplete, such that the economy is still far away from a
self-sustaining growth path. In the autumn of 2014, Greece finally achieved a primary
surplus and positive, albeit tepid growth of real GDP. The detailed and
carefully drafted reports by the Troika provide a balanced account of the
reform progress and remaining requirements. What Greece needed most in these
circumstances was a visible display of reliability. After all, uncertainty had
still been hampering domestic and foreign investors from engaging in Greece .
Unfortunately,
any sign of stability has effectively been wiped away by the new Greek
government. Blaming the recent capital flight from Greece and the sharp increase in
government yield spreads on anything else but the election-campaign
announcements and post-election decisions of Syriza would be ludicrous.
Debt relief
is unnecessary for Greece
In the
context of sovereign debt, debt sustainability has to be understood primarily
as (a society’s) willingness to pay. In the current situation the question
whether the Greek government is exercising its sovereign prerogative to declare
a (partial) default is most of all a matter of how the Greek government is
assessing the trade-off between the instant relief generated by declaring default
and its future ability to attract new lenders. Contemplating default would only
be sensible if this avoided a negative spiral that would otherwise force the
debtor to accumulate ever more debt to service the debt already accumulated.
Two aspects
dominate this issue: the debt already incurred vis-à-vis the economy's current
income (i.e. the debt-to-GDP ratio), and the difference between the interest
rate and the growth rate of income. Economies might in fact be able to sustain
a very high debt ratio if the relevant interest rate is low compared to the
growth rate. In this respect, Greece
is not overburdened, mainly due to the debt restructurings already conducted in
March 2012 for private creditors (Private Sector Involvement, PSI) and in
November 2012 regarding public creditors. Even more important than the PSI was
the willingness of Euro-member states to provide Greece with loans maturing as late
as decades away and carrying very low interest rates, partially even deferring
interest payments to the future as well. As a result, Greece enjoys
quite palatable debt service requirements, with an average interest rate of
2.3% and interest payments of 4% of GDP, and the major share of interest
payments is even deferred until the early 2020s. This is in fact substantially
lower than the debt service requirements faced by some of its lenders, such as Italy , with an
average interest rate of 3.3% and interest payments of 4.3% of GDP. A debt
relief of public creditors could not substantially improve the comfortable state
of the Greek government, let alone be justified easily vis-à-vis its lenders.
Beware of
‘political contagion’
Compared to
2010, negotiations with Greece
take place in a substantially changed institutional environment and under very
different economic circumstances. In 2010 a Grexit – Greece leaving the Eurozone to
return to its own currency – in all likelihood would have led to contagion in
sovereign debt markets of other member countries. In fact, the rescue package
put together for Greece
could not prevent Portugal
and Ireland
from losing market access soon thereafter and having to request financial
support as well. At the time, member states displayed an impressive commitment
to preserving the integrity of the currency union.
Today the
situation is very different. First, and above all, the newly established
institutional framework, most importantly the Banking Union and the ESM,
already provides a strong proof of such a commitment. Second, Greece ’s main
creditors are the member states, and the European banking sector is in much
better shape than in 2010. Third, member countries to which contagion spread in
2010 and afterwards, notably Ireland, Portugal, and Spain, but also Italy, are
in a much better economic situation, mainly due to fiscal adjustments and
structural reforms. Fourth, the ECB announced the outright monetary
transactions (OMT) programme and started a quantitative easing (QE) programme.
Given this progress, it is highly unlikely that international investors will
again start doubting the integrity of the Eurozone – with or without Greece
remaining a Eurozone member. Hence, the impact of Greece leaving the Eurozone seems
manageable.
Yet despite
these changes, the new Greek government is playing the Grexit card in current
negotiations, obviously betting on generating contagion fears. But the Greek
negotiators could hardly err more. In today’s situation, a Grexit, even if
unintended by the Greek government, has the potential to even strengthen the
institutional framework and the integrity of the Eurozone rather than spark
chaos outside Greece .
The
contagion to fear at this time concerns politics. Suppose the Eurozone were to
adopt the Greek government’s view that the austerity and structural reform
approach they have pursued jointly since 2010 was wrong, and were to reverse
course. This would strengthen radical political forces in other member
countries. Several governments might well be replaced by parties falsely
promising that market-oriented reforms and fiscal adjustment could be avoided.
In all likelihood, investors’ trust in the Eurozone’s commitment to create
conditions for sustainable growth would be lost. Such ‘political contagion’
could well trigger massive capital flows out of the Eurozone as a whole and
call its future existence into question.
A way
forward
What shall Greece do?
Certainly, the worst move would be to return to the economic structures that it
displayed as late as 2010. Especially relying on a large share of state
employment would be a recipe for disaster. The Greek public needs to realise
that things could actually become much worse than they are now, particularly if
membership in the Eurozone could not be assured. Instead of looking back, Greece needs to
continue building a functioning state and a functioning market economy.
A case in
point is the tax system. The Troika has helped install an effective system of
tax collection, which had not existed before and is still in the making. In
that sense, it has supported the Greek authorities in collecting taxes from
wealthy Greek citizens, as planned by Syriza, rather than preventing it. Greece is
suffering very hard times. But the real tragedy is that it elected a government
that threatens to exacerbate the situation and spoil the looming economic
recovery, on the basis of a thoroughly wrong assessment of its current
bargaining situation and the policy alternatives available for achieving
sustainable growth in Greece
and the Eurozone.
References
Corsetti, G
(2012), “Has Austerity gone too far?”, VoxEU.org, 2 April.
European
Commission (2012), “The Second Economic Adjustment Programme for Greece ”,
European Economy – Occasional Paper 94.
Purfield, C
and C B Rosenberg (2010), “Adjustment under a Currency Peg: Estonia , Latvia
and Lithuania
during the Global Financial Crisis 2008–09”, IMF Working Paper 10/213.
Stiglitz, J
E (2015), “A Greek Morality Tale”, Project Syndicate, 3 February.
Wolf, M
(2013), “How Austerity Has Failed”, New
York Review of Books 60(12), 11 July.
No comments:
Post a Comment