By SIMON
NIXON
Nov. 10,
2013 9:06 p.m. ET
The Wall Street Journal
On almost
any measure, the euro zone is in better shape than a year ago—and much better
shape than many expected, not least those who were predicting its imminent
collapse.
The currency
bloc is out of recession; Spain
and Portugal
are growing; the Greek government expects growth to return next year. Yields on
peripheral government bonds have fallen sharply. And the euro zone is embarking
on a major integration project—banking union—that it hopes will restore
confidence in the region's banking system and allow credit to flow again.
But every
silver lining has a cloud. In recent weeks, critics have identified a new
euro-zone fault line: Southern Europe , they
say, is being strangled by a combination of deflation and German mercantilism.
The U.S. Treasury last week pointed to Germany 's vast current-account
surplus of 7% of gross domestic product in 2012 as evidence that the country
should be doing more to boost domestic demand and reduce its reliance on
exports at a time when other euro-zone countries are being forced to implement
austerity policies.
But to some
European eyes, this new assault is as misdirected as past criticism of the euro
zone's crisis response. It's true that annual euro-zone inflation fell to just
0.7% in September, well below consensus forecasts of 1.2%. That prompted the
European Central Bank to cut its refinancing rate to just 0.25%. But few
economists think the euro zone is on the brink of a Japanese-style deflationary
spiral in which consumers hold off purchases in expectation of falling prices.
The euro
zone's current low inflation is different. To the extent that low inflation in Southern Europe is the result of domestic policy as
opposed to external factors such as the recent fall in energy costs, it partly
reflects consumer prices adjusting to falls in real wages. This is healthy. In
a currency union, falling labor costs are one of the main ways countries can
regain competitiveness. It would be more worrying if wages were falling and
prices still rising—as they have been in Greece —since this indicates a lack
of flexibility in markets and a rising burden of private-sector debt.
Of course,
it doesn't help that the euro appreciated over the summer. But euro-zone policy
makers blame this largely on the U.S. Federal Reserve's decision to keep
printing money alongside concerns that the U.S. might even default on its
debts. The best help the U.S.
could give Southern Europe would be to stop
weakening the dollar.
What is
less certain to help Southern Europe is action by Berlin
to reduce Germany 's
current-account surplus. German policy makers are bemused by the suggestion
that Germany 's surpluses
pose a similar problem to those of China in the last decade. After
all, Germany
doesn't operate a fixed exchange rate and isn't accumulating vast official
reserves. Its surpluses are the result of competitiveness gains painfully
achieved via a decade of reform and wage restraint during the years when it was
seen as the "sick man of Europe ."
What does
the U.S. want Germany to do?
Quit the euro? Make itself uncompetitive again, perhaps by forcing up wages?
How would that help Southern Europe ? Indeed,
in an increasingly integrated single market, focusing on Germany 's
surplus in isolation is simplistic. Other member states have benefited from
German competitiveness gains because they are integrated into Germany 's
supply chain or have received direct German investment.
Perhaps the
Treasury thinks Germany
could help Southern Europe by embarking on a
public-spending splurge? But Germany
fiscal policy is hardly contractionary: Whatever government emerges from the
current coalition talks is likely to pursue a balanced budget. Only the most
fervent Keynesians would argue that Germany , with a government
debt-to-GDP ratio of 82%, has fiscal space to fund a stimulus package. It's
hard to find policy makers in Southern Europe
clamoring for a new German road-building program.
Besides,
this focus on Germany 's
current-account position risks obscuring the real issues. A sustained recovery
in Southern Europe hinges on businesses having the confidence to start
investing again after five years of underinvestment, including in Germany . This
in turn will give consumers the confidence to start spending, causing
deflationary pressures to ease and Germany 's current-account deficit
to shrink.
But for
businesses to start spending, they need confirmation that governments are
serious about tackling the root causes of the crisis: That means creating a
credible banking union and pushing ahead with structural overhauls to boost
competitiveness.
Both
objectives currently hang in the balance. Over the next few weeks, euro-zone
leaders face difficult decisions on bank resolution arrangements and common
backstops for the ECB's forthcoming comprehensive assessment and stress testing
of bank balance sheets. Done properly, this exercise will drive the
recapitalization and restructuring needed to revive funding markets and ensure
banks are able to support a recovery.
Indeed,
there are signs that in some countries, efforts to clear up the banking system
are already delivering results. The recent fall in Spanish bank deposit rates
may deliver a bigger economic boost than last week's ECB rate cut as it feeds
directly to bank profits and the pricing of new loans, while the surge in
investor appetite for Spanish assets will help banks deleverage. But other
peripheral-country banking systems remain stressed.
Meanwhile
progress on reforms has been patchy: Spain
has gone furthest toward restoring its competitiveness, reflected in buoyant
exports; Portugal and Greece have
also made valuable changes. But Italy
has failed to make any improvement to its competitiveness or productivity since
the start of the crisis.
But this
too may be changing: The current Southern European governments know what they
need to do—and they have all survived political crises this year and appear to
be much more stable than seemed possible a few months ago. Even in Italy , some
argue that the waning influence of former Prime Minister Silvio Berlusconi is
creating political space for more radical reforms.
Even so,
the domestic obstacles to reform are considerable. Recent history suggests
external pressure can certainly play a useful role in pushing Europeans to act
decisively. But those efforts would be better directed to urging weak economies
to make themselves strong, rather than urging Europe 's
strongest economy to make itself weak.
Write to
Simon Nixon at simon.nixon@wsj.com
No comments:
Post a Comment