Posted By
Park MacDougald Tuesday, July 16, 2013
- 7:45 PM
Foreign
Policy
Another
day, another ballooning corruption scandal in southern Europe .
On Monday, the former treasurer of Spain's ruling center-right Popular Party
(PP), Luis Bárcenas, admitted in court to authoring handwritten ledgers
detailing the secret flow of cash from private firms to top-level officials in
the PP. Bárcenas also alleged, after months of speculation in the media, that
Spanish Prime Minister Mariano Rajoy accepted regular payments from the illegal
slush fund.
A day after
Bárcenas's damning testimony, the opposition Socialist Party has threatened to
call a vote of no-confidence against the prime minister -- a symbolic gesture
given the PP's dominant parliamentary majority. And while it's unclear whether
the scandal will bring down Rajoy's government, it has played into the common
narrative these days about the connection between government corruption and
economic stagnation in Europe 's periphery. As
the BBC notes, the revelations in Spain "have enraged a country
in the depths of recession and record unemployment."
But just
what is the relationship between malfeasance and economic performance? The
answer might surprise you.
Corruption
is certainly widespread in southern Europe .
According to Transparency International's Global Corruption Barometer 2013,
perceptions of corruption and faith in government institutions are on the rise
in the region, with 83 percent of respondents in Greece ,
70 percent in Italy , and 66
percent in Spain
claiming that "government is run by a few big interests." Conversely,
few believe their governments are effective in fighting graft, and many blame
this culture of corruption for the region's struggling economies. The
technocratic governments of Greek Prime Minister Antonis Samaras and former
Italian Prime Minister Mario Monti both made anti-corruption central to their
agendas for economic growth, and the PP's recent troubles indicate that Spain may be
headed down the same path.
Yet while
corruption is undesirable for moral and symbolic reasons (it erodes faith in
government, among other things), some academic research suggests that
corruption can be good for economies -- or, at least, not as bad as is
generally assumed.
According
to a 2006 study by Fabio Méndez and Facundo Sepúlveda, there is no linear
relationship between corruption and economic growth in regimes rated as
"free" by Freedom House. In fact, the economists find that the
"growth-maximizing level of corruption [in free countries] is
significantly greater than zero, with corruption beneficial for economic growth
at low levels of incidence," while also conceding that abnormally high
levels of corruption are damaging regardless of government type.
In
addition, a 2008 paper by Toke Aidt, Jayasri Dutta, and Vania Sena finds that
the quality of institutions in a given country is a major determinant of the
effects of corruption. In countries with deficient institutions, corruption has
little to no effect on economic growth, because voters cannot punish corrupt
politicians. In countries with relatively strong democratic institutions, the
researchers conclude that corruption does damage growth, but also that economic
growth itself is a strong guarantor of reducing corruption, because it means
that "the resource base from which leaders extract rents expands over
time."
"This
makes them more eager to hold on to political power," they continue,
"and creates a benign feedback loop between economic growth and
corruption: high growth reduces corruption which, in turn, increases
growth."
Neither
paper is a ringing endorsement of corruption -- although Méndez and Sepúlveda
do note a "growth-maximizing" level of graft - and Aidt, Dutta, and
Sena are quick to dispel notions that corruption has a net positive impact on
economies. It should also be noted that the academic literature on corruption
is mixed at both the theoretical and empirical level, so both should be taken
with a grain of salt.
Nevertheless,
what these studies suggest is that, by itself, corruption is much less
important for a country's economic health than outside factors like the quality
of its institutions, the degree of political freedom, and government policy or
the state of the national and global economy. As Aidt, Dutta, and Sena put it,
"the relationship between corruption and growth is regime specific."
Or, to put
it in the context of the current European Union: While anti-corruption measures
are probably a net positive in the long run (not to mention an essential PR
move in countries rightly seething with anger at their elites), they can also
be something of a red herring; in European countries decimated by austerity,
teetering banks, and the loss of independent monetary policy, corruption is a
secondary issue. And, given the role economic growth plays in reducing
corruption, a country looking to clean up its image isn't likely to get there
through 9 percent across-the-board spending cuts.
No comments:
Post a Comment