It’s time
to think more seriously about this possibility.
The Wall
Street Journal
By RICHARD
BARWELL
April 1,
2015 3:48 p.m. ET
The 24-hour
news cycle is causing a cacophony of speculation about Greece leaving
the euro, the so-called Grexit. Amid all the arguments about whether Greece will or should exit, there has been a lot
less thought given to what would happen if Greece does return to the drachma.
It’s time to think more seriously about this possibility.
A Greek
exit would have far-reaching consequences for the eurozone, weakening the ties
that bind the single currency together in some respects, strengthening them in
others. On balance the latter will probably dominate, reducing the chance that
other countries leave. If Greece
leaves the eurozone, it would create a number of precedents that would
influence how people vote and politicians behave elsewhere in Europe .
If the
Greek people choose to leave in a referendum, they will send a powerful signal
that they, and not the central bankers, officials and politicians in Frankfurt,
Brussels and Berlin hold the destiny of the euro in their
hands. But if it’s the Greek politicians who make the decision to leave, based
on an electoral mandate rather than a referendum, that could make voters
elsewhere think twice before voting for antiausterity candidates.
There will
be lessons for politicians about the dangers of brinkmanship, especially if a
Grexit happens almost by accident. If the funding problems facing the
government and the banks escalate out of control, capital controls would be
triggered, making a vote on Greece’s future—whether by Parliamentary elections
or a referendum—far more likely. Politicians in smaller economies might in
future be more likely to cut a deal with creditors, and politicians in creditor
countries might be more likely to offer better deals, including debt relief.
After all, Greece
would almost certainly unilaterally default on its debts when it leaves.
Meanwhile,
a Grexit would resolve the uncertainty over how to leave the single currency.
The euro wasn’t designed with an easily accessible escape hatch. If Greece does
leave, it will establish a precedent, but not one that others may wish to
emulate, since it might also have to leave the European Union too.
Most
important of all, a Grexit might set an economic precedent. If the Greek
economy should recover after leaving the eurozone, it would be much harder to
convince others that they should stay.
However, a
painful economic afterlife seems far more likely. The Greek economy would get
caught in a pincer, with a sharp and sustained contraction in credit and an
increase in uncertainty propelling the economy back into a deep recession.
There would be a significant risk of further, lasting damage to the Greek
economy through the destruction of jobs and companies.
Even the
sharp depreciation in the currency would be a double-edged sword. There would
be a painful squeeze on disposable income as imports become much more
expensive. This would at least partly offset the boost to Greek exports,
assuming companies elsewhere in the eurozone don’t reroute supply chains out of
Greece
to avoid invoices billed in drachma. Likewise, it is brave to assume that there
would be an influx of foreign capital until the political and economic
uncertainty has been resolved.
Beyond
these near-term challenges, there are two important medium-term consequences to
consider.
A
post-Grexit eurozone would be more susceptible to the kind of speculative
attack on the currency union that took place in 2012. Given a resumption of
sovereign stress in smaller countries, investors would quickly start to demand
sizeable compensation for the risk that they may not be paid in euros in a
future break-up scenario. Spending would grind to a halt and capital would fly
out of the countries concerned.
The
European Central Bank’s most potent policy tool, its quantitative easing
program, isn’t designed to deal with this problem, and the instrument that
is—the Outright Monetary Transactions program to buy a small set of sovereign
bonds in the secondary market—may not be big enough to stabilize markets in a
future crisis. The OMT can only be used to save countries that commit to saving
themselves by driving through reforms.
We should
expect a political response to fight those forces threatening to pull the
eurozone apart. A Grexit could ultimately bring the union closer together, with
fiscal union and common debt issuance going hand in hand with binding and
credible commitments on structural reforms helping to turn the eurozone into an
optimal and far more stable currency area.
This is all
moot if Greece ’s
leaders hammer out a deal with creditors and avert an exit from the eurozone.
But prudent policy makers and investors should spend some time considering how they
would answer some of the questions that a Grexit might raise.
Mr. Barwell
is the senior European economist at Royal Bank of Scotland .
No comments:
Post a Comment