By George Soros
Reutrers
The opinions expressed are his
own.
The euro crisis is a direct
consequence of the crash of 2008. When Lehman Brothers failed, the entire
financial system started to collapse and had to be put on artificial life
support. This took the form of substituting the sovereign credit of governments
for the bank and other credit that had collapsed. At a memorable meeting of
European finance ministers in November 2008, they guaranteed that no other
financial institutions that are important to the workings of the financial
system would be allowed to fail, and their example was followed by the United States .
Angela Merkel then declared
that the guarantee should be exercised by each European state individually, not
by the European Union or the eurozone acting as a whole. This sowed the seeds
of the euro crisis because it revealed and activated a hidden weakness in the
construction of the euro: the lack of a common treasury. The crisis itself
erupted more than a year later, in 2010.
There is some similarity
between the euro crisis and the subprime crisis that caused the crash of 2008.
In each case a supposedly riskless asset—collateralized debt obligations
(CDOs), based largely on mortgages, in 2008, and European government bonds
now—lost some or all of their value.
Unfortunately the euro crisis
is more intractable. In 2008 the U.S. financial authorities that
were needed to respond to the crisis were in place; at present in the eurozone
one of these authorities, the common treasury, has yet to be brought into
existence. This requires a political process involving a number of sovereign
states. That is what has made the problem so severe. The political will to
create a common European treasury was absent in the first place; and since the
time when the euro was created the political cohesion of the European Union has
greatly deteriorated. As a result there is no clearly visible solution to the
euro crisis. In its absence the authorities have been trying to buy time.
In an ordinary financial
crisis this tactic works: with the passage of time the panic subsides and
confidence returns. But in this case time has been working against the
authorities. Since the political will is missing, the problems continue to grow
larger while the politics are also becoming more poisonous.
It takes a crisis to make the
politically impossible possible. Under the pressure of a financial crisis the
authorities take whatever steps are necessary to hold the system together, but
they only do the minimum and that is soon perceived by the financial markets as
inadequate. That is how one crisis leads to another. So Europe
is condemned to a seemingly unending series of crises. Measures that would have
worked if they had they been adopted earlier turn out to be inadequate by the
time they become politically possible. This is the key to understanding the
euro crisis.
Where are we now in this
process? The outlines of the missing ingredient, namely a common treasury, are
beginning to emerge. They are to be found in the European Financial Stability
Facility (EFSF)—agreed on by twenty-seven member states of the EU in May
2010—and its successor, after 2013, the European Stability Mechanism (ESM). But
the EFSF is not adequately capitalized and its functions are not adequately defined.
It is supposed to provide a safety net for the eurozone as a whole, but in
practice it has been tailored to finance the rescue packages for three small
countries: Greece, Portugal, and Ireland; it is not large enough to support
bigger countries like Spain or Italy. Nor was it originally meant to deal with
the problems of the banking system, although its scope has subsequently been
extended to include banks as well as sovereign states. Its biggest shortcoming
is that it is purely a fund-raising mechanism; the authority to spend the money
is left with the governments of the member countries. This renders the EFSF
useless in responding to a crisis; it has to await instructions from the member
countries.
The situation has been further
aggravated by the recent decision of the German Constitutional Court . While the
court found that the EFSF is constitutional, it prohibited any future
guarantees benefiting additional states without the prior approval of the
budget committee of the Bundestag. This will greatly constrain the
discretionary powers of the German government in confronting future crises.
The seeds of the next crisis
have already been sown by the way the authorities responded to the last crisis.
They accepted the principle that countries receiving assistance should not have
to pay punitive interest rates and they set up the EFSF as a fund-raising
mechanism for this purpose. Had this principle been accepted in the first
place, the Greek crisis would not have grown so severe. As it is, the
contagion—in the form of increasing inability to pay sovereign and other
debt—has spread to Spain and Italy, but those countries are not allowed to
borrow at the lower, concessional rates extended to Greece. This has set them
on a course that will eventually land them in the same predicament as Greece . In the
case of Greece ,
the debt burden has clearly become unsustainable. Bondholders have been offered
a “voluntary” restructuring by which they would accept lower interest rates and
delayed or decreased repayments; but no other arrangements have been made for a
possible default or for defection from the eurozone.
These two deficiencies—no
concessional rates for Italy or Spain and no preparation for a possible default
and defection from the eurozone by Greece—have cast a heavy shadow of doubt
both on the government bonds of other deficit countries and on the banking
system of the eurozone, which is loaded with those bonds. As a stopgap measure
the European Central Bank (ECB) stepped into the breach by buying Spanish and Italian
bonds in the market. But that is not a viable solution. The ECB had done the
same thing for Greece ,
but that did not stop the Greek debt from becoming unsustainable. If Italy , with its
debt at 108 percent of GDP and growth of less than 1 percent, had to pay risk
premiums of 3 percent or more to borrow money, its debt would also become
unsustainable.
The ECB’s earlier decision to
buy Greek bonds had been highly controversial; Axel Weber, the ECB’s German
board member, resigned from the board in protest. The intervention did blur the
line between monetary and fiscal policy, but a central bank is supposed to do
whatever is necessary to preserve the financial system. That is particularly
true in the absence of a fiscal authority. Subsequently, the controversy led
the ECB to adamantly oppose a restructuring of Greek debt—by which, among other
measures, the time for repayment would be extended—turning the ECB from a
savior of the system into an obstructionist force. The ECB has prevailed: the
EFSF took over the risk of possible insolvency of the Greek bonds from the ECB.
The resolution of this dispute
has in turn made it easier for the ECB to embark on its current program to
purchase Italian and Spanish bonds, which, unlike those of Greece, are not
about to default. Still, the decision has encountered the same internal
opposition from Germany
as the earlier intervention in Greek bonds. Jürgen Stark, the chief economist
of the ECB, resigned on September 9. In any case the current intervention has
to be limited in scope because the capacity of the EFSF to extend help is
virtually exhausted by the rescue operations already in progress in Greece , Portugal ,
and Ireland .
In the meantime the Greek
government is having increasing difficulties in meeting the conditions imposed
by the assistance program. The troika supervising the program—the EU, the IMF,
and the ECB—is not satisfied; Greek banks did not fully subscribe to the latest
treasury bill auction; and the Greek government is running out of funds.
In these circumstances an
orderly default and temporary withdrawal from the eurozone may be preferable to
a drawn-out agony. But no preparations have been made. A disorderly default
could precipitate a meltdown similar to the one that followed the bankruptcy of
Lehman Brothers, but this time one of the authorities that would be needed to
contain it is missing.
No wonder that the financial
markets have taken fright. Risk premiums that must be paid to buy government
bonds have increased, stocks have plummeted, led by bank stocks, and recently
even the euro has broken out of its trading range on the downside. The
volatility of markets is reminiscent of the crash of 2008.
Unfortunately the capacity of
the financial authorities to take the measures necessary to contain the crisis has
been severely restricted by the recent ruling of the German Constitutional Court . It appears
that the authorities have reached the end of the road with their policy of
“kicking the can down the road.” Even if a catastrophe can be avoided, one
thing is certain: the pressure to reduce deficits will push the eurozone into
prolonged recession. This will have incalculable political consequences. The
euro crisis could endanger the political cohesion of the European Union.
There is no escape from this
gloomy scenario as long as the authorities persist in their current course.
They could, however, change course. They could recognize that they have reached
the end of the road and take a radically different approach. Instead of
acquiescing in the absence of a solution and trying to buy time, they could
look for a solution first and then find a path leading to it. The path that
leads to a solution has to be found in Germany ,
which, as the EU’s largest and highest-rated creditor country, has been thrust
into the position of deciding the future of Europe .
That is the approach I propose to explore.
To resolve a crisis in which
the impossible becomes possible it is necessary to think about the unthinkable.
To start with, it is imperative to prepare for the possibility of default and
defection from the eurozone in the case of Greece ,
Portugal , and perhaps Ireland .
To prevent a financial
meltdown, four sets of measures would have to be taken. First, bank deposits
have to be protected. If a euro deposited in a Greek bank would be lost to the
depositor, a euro deposited in an Italian bank would then be worth less than
one in a German or Dutch bank and there would be a run on the banks of other
deficit countries. Second, some banks in the defaulting countries have to be
kept functioning in order to keep the economy from breaking down. Third, the
European banking system would have to be recapitalized and put under European,
as distinct from national, supervision. Fourth, the government bonds of the
other deficit countries would have to be protected from contagion. The last two
requirements would apply even if no country defaults.
All this would cost money.
Under existing arrangements no more money is to be found and no new
arrangements are allowed by the German
Constitutional Court decision without the
authorization of the Bundestag. There is no alternative but to give birth to
the missing ingredient: a European treasury with the power to tax and therefore
to borrow. This would require a new treaty, transforming the EFSF into a full-fledged
treasury.
That would presuppose a
radical change of heart, particularly in Germany . The German public still
thinks that it has a choice about whether to support the euro or to abandon it.
That is a mistake. The euro exists and the assets and liabilities of the
financial system are so intermingled on the basis of a common currency that a
breakdown of the euro would cause a meltdown beyond the capacity of the
authorities to contain. The longer it takes for the German public to realize
this, the heavier the price they and the rest of the world will have to pay.
The question is whether the
German public can be convinced of this argument. Angela Merkel may not be able
to persuade her own coalition, but she could rely on the opposition. Having
resolved the euro crisis, she would have less to fear from the next elections.
The fact that arrangements are
made for the possible default or defection of three small countries does not
mean that those countries would be abandoned. On the contrary, the possibility of
an orderly default—paid for by the other eurozone countries and the IMF—would
offer Greece and Portugal policy
choices. Moreover, it would end the vicious cycle now threatening all of the
eurozone’s deficit countries whereby austerity weakens their growth prospects,
leading investors to demand prohibitively high interest rates and thus forcing
their governments to cut spending further.
Leaving the euro would make it
easier for them to regain competitiveness; but if they are willing to make the
necessary sacrifices they could also stay in. In both cases, the EFSF would
protect bank deposits and the IMF would help to recapitalize the banking
system. That would help these countries to escape from the trap in which they
currently find themselves. It would be against the best interests of the
European Union to allow these countries to collapse and drag down the global
banking system with them.
It is not for me to spell out
the details of the new treaty; that has to be decided by the member countries.
But the discussions ought to start right away because even under extreme
pressure they will take a long time to conclude. Once the principle of setting
up a European Treasury is agreed upon, the European Council could authorize the
ECB to step into the breach, indemnifying the ECB in advance against risks to
its solvency. That is the only way to forestall a possible financial meltdown
and another Great Depression.
This essay is reprinted with
permission from the author, and from the New York Review of Books, where it was
originally published.
PHOTO: A woman walks past a
pizza shop with a sign of a euro coin used to advertise its prices in central Madrid , September 13,
2011. REUTERS/Paul Hanna
No comments:
Post a Comment