8 MAY 28, 2015 7:24 AM EDT
By Leonid Bershidsky
The idea of
a parallel currency for Greece is worthy of consideration, with even German
Finance Minister Wolfgang Schaeuble broaching the possibility as Greece fails
to reach an agreement with its creditors. It could work -- albeit not in the
way suggested by the pretty models circulated by economists in recent months.
Most of
these involve Greece
issuing some form of IOUs to pay its employees and contractors, with the
government accepting these new securities in lieu of taxes at some future date.
The specific designs differ (here is a good summary of some of them, and here
is a more or less exhaustive classification of parallel currency proposals for
the euro area), and there are interesting twists. Before he became Greek
finance minister, Yanis Varoufakis suggested discounting the parallel currency
-- he called it FT-coin, short for future taxes -- for euros. People would buy
it because they'd be able to use 1,000 euros in FT-coins to pay 1500 euros
worth of taxes in two years.
No matter
what design frills economists tack on to the plans, the general idea is the
same: The government would pay people in something other than money, but it
would create an incentive for them to use that surrogate as a medium of
exchange. Otherwise, the logic goes, nobody would accept it.
The problem
with this train of thought is that in Greece , tax credits are not a huge
enticement. Greeks are not particularly diligent taxpayers. At the end of last
year, they owed the state 76 billion euros ($83 billion) in unpaid levies. Tax
evasion is rampant, giving rise to exotic ideas like using housewives, students
and even foreign tourists as freelance tax inspectors. If you're not going to
pay taxes, you won't pay for tax credits even on the best of terms. Even if the
scheme were workable, it would sow the seeds of a new crisis in a few years,
once the government started getting back its IOUs instead of genuine tax
revenue.
Anyone who
has ever lived behind the Iron Curtain knows that the right way to run a
parallel currency is based on coercion, not enticement.
Such a
system persists in Cuba .
That country uses the "convertible peso," or CUC, along with the
Cuban peso, or CUP. Foreign tourists exchange their dollars (or, preferably,
euros, pounds or yen, given the 10 percent tax on dollar trades) for CUC, which
can be used in the "hard currency economy" -- to pay for imported
goods, for gas, in tourist-oriented restaurants. Cubans are paid in CUP, which
they can spend in local stores (mostly to buy rationed produce) and on
services. They are allowed to convert CUP to CUC at a set rate reasonably close
to the market one. That's an improvement on, say, the Soviet system, in which
you could not legally convert rubles into foreign currency, except in a few
special situations and at an extremely unfavorable rate. Still, most Cubans
cannot afford to live the CUC life: The average salary on the island is the
equivalent of $20 per month.
Like
previous Communist systems, the Cuban one is a pain in the neck to administer,
and the government has been promising since 2013 to scrap it. When the Cuban
peso is finally unified, the country will still have a parallel currency
system, with the dollar unofficially dislodging the CUC. The logic of the
situation is that convertible currencies are for those who want access to
imports. The government does not encourage that access, but it's still somewhat
integrated into the global economy and it wants its elite to have access to
nice clothes, good whisky and Swiss chocolate. Therefore, there's a local
currency for proles and a convertible one for bosses.
If that
doesn't sound very left-wing, it's not just because the practice of leftist
ideas tends to be vastly different from the theory. Look at it from a different
perspective: A government that wants to provide a minimum standard of living
for all its citizens but doesn't have the resources must quarantine its
currency system from the rest of the world. Why shouldn't Greece 's
hard-left government give its citizens a taste of Cuban-style currency duality?
There's plenty of food and clothing produced inside the country that cannot be
profitably exported. The government could charge for its services in drachmas,
or whatever the new parallel currency would be called. Other service providers
would have no alternative to taking the soft currency because the 20 percent of
the Greek labor force employed in the public sector, including state companies,
would only be paid in drachmas. In fact, the government could drastically
reduce unemployment by hiring the jobless and paying them in its new currency.
This would,
of course, create the potential for hyperinflation, and the government would
need to impose exchange restrictions. A black market would immediately spring
up, as it did in Ukraine
last year under similar circumstances. Ukrainians, however, discovered that
unless they planned to travel or buy expensive imports, they could get by just
fine with the local currency.
Ugly? Yes, but one could argue that Greeks hate the
alternatives -- austerity and fiscal discipline -- even more than they would
hate this taste of Soviet medicine. That's why they elected a determined
left-wing government to lead them and fight international creditors every inch
of the way.
And once Greece got
tired of its parallel currency, it could drop the drachma and go back to using
the euro. Montenegro
scrapped the Yugoslav dinar in favor of the deutsche mark in 1996 and Ecuador dropped
the sucre for the U.S. dollar in 2000 because de-facto parallel currency
regimes were deemed unnecessary. There are also more or less successful
examples of post-Communist transitions to single convertible currencies. Cast
back into the developing world, Greece
shouldn't be shy to learn from its new peers.
To contact
the author on this story:
Leonid
Bershidsky at lbershidsky@bloomberg.net
To contact
the editor on this story:
Mark
Gilbert at magilbert@bloomberg.net
No comments:
Post a Comment