MAY 29,
2015 2:00 AM EDT
By Mohamed
A. El-Erian
Bloomberg
Economics
and finance suffered two tragedies in the past week: the death of the Nobel
laureate John Nash and his wife in a horrible car accident, and more delays
from Greece
and its creditors in reaching an agreement on a path out of the costly and
protracted crisis.
A mutually
beneficial outcome would alleviate the long suffering of Greek citizens who
have been devastated by unemployment, shrinking incomes and spreading poverty.
It would also bolster the credibility, integrity and robustness of the euro
zone as a viable economic, financial and political entity. And it would remove
one of the uncertainties preventing the global economy from achieving a pace of
growth consistent with its potential.
At first
sight there seem to be little to link the two tragedies. Yet the game theory
insights that John Nash pioneered -- including the concept of a
"cooperative game" -- shed important light on what is happening in Greece , and
help explain why the drama is unlikely to have a happy ending anytime soon.
In a
cooperative game, players coordinate to achieve better outcomes than the ones
that would likely prevail in the absence of such coordination. If the game is
played uncooperatively, however, the result is unfortunate for all players.
This simple
idea accurately describes the protracted Greek drama, including the current
rush at the Group of Seven meeting in Germany to find yet another way to
kick the can down the road.
At the
simplest level of analysis, Greece
is seeking to regain economic growth, create jobs and restore its financial
viability, while remaining part of the single currency. Its European partners,
working with the International Monetary Fund, share these goals, so long as
achieving them doesn't impose a disproportionately heavy burden on other euro
zone states in terms of finances and political acceptability, and by setting a
poor example for future crises.
The
problem, in game theory terms, is that a game that needs to be played
cooperatively to achieve the desired outcome continues to be played
uncooperatively -- repeatedly. The reasons for this unfortunate state of
affairs are understandable:
There is little trust between Greece and its creditors (in this case, the
European Central Bank, the European Union , and
the IMF).
The sides haven't defined a common
understanding of the problem, even less a solution.
The process for ensuring that policy and
financing commitments are met is patchy and often controversial, in part
because of political undertones: The
Greek government doesn't want to be perceived as subservient to other European
nations and those countries don't want be viewed as financial hostages to the inadequacy
of Greek policies.
And the functioning of the coalition of
creditors (once known as the Troika) is far from smooth.
Thoughtful
economists such as the Nobel laureate Michael Spence have extended this concept
of a cooperative game being played uncooperatively to the broader dysfunctions
influencing the global economy. This type of game points to costs that far
exceed simply suboptimal outcomes; it also entails the possibility of
collateral damage and unintended consequences.
There are
at least four ways to transform uncooperative games into cooperative ones.
Unfortunately, these approaches would be ineffective in the case of Greece .
One
involves using two-sided and mutually supportive conditionality as the
transformation agent: for example, by rewarding the implementation of economic
reforms with the ready availability of external financing. This has been tried
in Greece ,
but the results have fallen short, which has diminished the effectiveness of
this tool. Specifically, Greece 's
record on making good on its policy-reform promises has been far from perfect;
and its creditors have been too hesitant in providing the extent of debt relief
and cash the country needs.
A second
way involves a decisive external impetus. In the case of Greece and its
creditors, this role has been played by fear, particularly the fear that the
Greek economy would implode, which would force it out of the euro zone. This
has stoked the additional fear that such an outcome would destabilize other
euro zone economies, threaten the integrity of the single currency group and
disrupt the global economy.
And fear is
an inconsistent transformation agent because its impact is hard to sustain. As
soon as it dissipates, all sides revert to uncooperative behavior. And this is
what has happened in this case since at least 2010.
A third
alternative involves the entry of new players that are willing and able to put
aside uncooperative legacies. In today's Europe ,
however, the political reality is that new players tend to be even more
skeptical than their predecessors. The electoral victory of Syriza in Greece is a
case in point.
Finally,
mutually beneficial developments could convince both sides to work together
more closely. Regrettably, this hasn’t been the case of Greece and its
European partners, given the limited progress on the ground.
Assessing
the Greek drama through the lens of game theory explains why the crisis -- and
the question of Greece 's
continued euro-zone membership -- are no closer to being resolved. Applying
Nash's theory shows that the best we can realistically expect is yet another
attempt to postpone painful decisions. But even this inadequate outcome is
proving increasingly difficult to deliver, and if it materializes, the
resulting delay will lead to an even more difficult situation, unless the
players decide to stop their uncooperative game very soon.
To contact
the author on this story:
Mohamed
El-Erian at melerian@bloomberg.net
To contact
the editor on this story:
Max Berley
at mberley@bloomberg.net
No comments:
Post a Comment